Impact of Brain Drain on Africa

Published on 8th January 2008

One central question that has caused a lot of controversy has been whether brain drain has positive or negative impact on developing countries.  Migration studies conducted in different parts of the world to assess the impact of intellectual migration have produced quite contradictory results. One divergent school of thought examines brain drain from the perspective of the highly detrimental effects arising from the loss of the brightest minds from developing countries, thus weakening capacity for development.  On the other hand, representatives of the convergence school of thought argue that the problem of brain drain is over dramatized and is less critical than it is usually portrayed.  They tend to emphasize the beneficial consequences of migration for both the receiving country and the sending country.

Economic Impact

Some authors hold that brain drain represents a major development constraint both in terms of development opportunities and lost investment and that it drains sending areas of their human capital that took enormous resources to nurture and produce. The country with outflow of emigrants, it is argued, loses critical human capital in which it has invested resources through education and specialized training and for which it is not compensated by the recipient country.  It is in this view that brain drain is often referred to as “an international transfer of resources in the form of human capital that is not recorded in any official balance of payments statistics.” For example, UNCTAD, has estimated that one highly trained African migrant between 25 – 35 years, the age group into which most of the Africans going abroad fall – represents a cash value of US$184,000 at 1997 prices.

 

The views aired by proponents of the divergent school of thought are that, the country of origin suffers a net loss because it funds the education and training of professionals who, precisely at the moment they start producing, decide to emigrate. Avveduto S. & Brandi, M.C. in Defining Brain Drain: The Evolution of Theories of Brain Drain and Migration of Skilled Personnel corroborate with the above sentiments by echoing that “the country that invests in human resources is not the one that enjoys the return on its investment”. Conversely, the receiving country obtains qualified workers without having to bear the costs of training them, and therefore makes a net gain. Africa’s education budget becomes nothing but a supplement to the education budgets for the West hence giving developmental assistance to the wealthier western nations, which makes the rich nations richer and the poor nations poorer.

There is a general belief that brain drain tends to pull the ‘best and the brightest from their home countries, the very people most equipped to help improve living conditions at home. This means a slow death for Africa.  Devesh Kapur and John MacHale argue in their book Give Us Your Best and Brightest published by the Centre for Global Development, that the loss of institution builders – hospital managers, university department heads and political reformers, among others – can help trap countries in poverty.

Africa needs a large middle class to build a large tax base which, in turn, will enable the continent to build good schools and hospitals and provide constant electricity. What few people do not realize is that Africans who immigrate to the United States contribute 40 times more wealth to the America than to the African economy.  According to the United Nations, an African professional working in the United States contributes about US$150,000 per year to the US economy. It will be impossible to achieve an African renaissance without the contributions of the talented Africans residing outside Africa.

The proponents of the convergence school of thought look at brain drain from a functionalist perspective. They argue that the human capital investment made in the high-level migrants are partly recovered through remittances. Although not many economy-wide studies have been conducted on the effects of migrant remittances on African countries, it is often emphasized that while emigration countries lose manpower and particularly the “best and brightest”, they also get something in return.  Migrants who work abroad usually send part of their income to their families in the home country.  They also contend that remittances promote development by improving income distribution and quality of life by loosening production and investment constraints faced by households in the sending countries; after all, migration decisions are part of family strategies to raise income, obtain funds to invest in new activities, and insure against income and production risks.

 

The economic impact of remittances has been considered beneficial at both the micro and macro levels. Harmele (1997, cited in Ammassari & Black, 2001:13) contends that the value of migrant remittances can significantly exceed that of national export earnings. Available estimates indicate that there has been rapid growth in the volume of global remittances in recent decades, from less than US$2 billion in 1970 to US$70 billion in 1995, surpassing official development assistance.  Some economists tout remittances as the developing world’s most reliable and broadly based source of financing, making it effectively a new form of foreign aid. A report by SIRDC (2004:74), also states that a beneficial aspect of the brain drain, if properly managed, is that it enables emigrants to send a part of their earnings home in the form of remittances, thus providing the home country with a source of valuable foreign currency. It has also been observed that the remittances can have a multiplier effect on the economy as a whole.  For example, in Mexico, the USD2 billion that were arriving in the country in the early 1990s are estimated to have increased overall annual production by USD6.5 billion (SIRDC, 2004:74).

Those who argue against the issue of remittances often emphasize their unproductive nature. They say, not only are remittances insufficient to compensate for human capital losses, they, increase dependency, contribute to political instability, engender economic distortions, and hinder development because they are unpredictable and undependable and encourage the consumption of goods with high import content. The remittances fail to enhance development because they are not spent on investment goods but mostly spent on unproductive purposes – housing, land purchase, transport, repayment of debt, or to a smaller degree wasted on conspicuous consumption, or simply saved as insurance and old age pension funds.

Emeagwali, who also spoke strongly against remittances emphasized the need to eliminate poverty in Africa, and not merely reducing it by sending money to relatives.  He reiterated that in any country, human capital is much more valuable than financial capital because it is only a nation’s human capital that can be converted into real wealth.  To quote his own words, Emeagwali says that Money alone cannot eliminate poverty in Africa, because even one million dollars is a number with no intrinsic value.  Real wealth cannot be measured by money, yet people often confuse money with wealth.  Under the status quo, Africa would still remain poor even if we were to send all the money in the world there.  When you give your money to your doctor, that physician helps you to convert your money into health – or rather wealth.  Money cannot teach your children, teachers can.  Money cannot bring electricity to your home, engineers can.  Money cannot cure sick people, doctors can. When the medical doctors emigrate to the United States, the poor are forced to seek medical treatment from traditional healers while the elite fly to London for their routine medical checkups.

“The reality”, Edward Taylor (1999, cited in Zeleza, 1998:19), correctly points out, “lies somewhere between these two extremes.”  It all depends on the context, countries, and communities involved.  In short, the relationship between migration and development is multidimensional and complex.


This article has been read 1,615 times
COMMENTS